Skip to main content
Menu

Main navigation

  • About
    • Annual Reports
    • Leadership
    • Jobs
    • Student Programs
    • Media Information
    • Store
    • Contact
    LOADING...
  • Experts
    • Policy Scholars
    • Adjunct Scholars
    • Fellows
  • Events
    • Upcoming
    • Past
    • Event FAQs
    • Sphere Summit
    LOADING...
  • Publications
    • Studies
    • Commentary
    • Books
    • Reviews and Journals
    • Public Filings
    LOADING...
  • Blog
  • Donate
    • Sponsorship Benefits
    • Ways to Give
    • Planned Giving

Issues

  • Constitution and Law
    • Constitutional Law
    • Criminal Justice
    • Free Speech and Civil Liberties
  • Economics
    • Banking and Finance
    • Monetary Policy
    • Regulation
    • Tax and Budget Policy
  • Politics and Society
    • Education
    • Government and Politics
    • Health Care
    • Poverty and Social Welfare
    • Technology and Privacy
  • International
    • Defense and Foreign Policy
    • Global Freedom
    • Immigration
    • Trade Policy
Live Now

Cato at Liberty


  • Blog Home
  • RSS

Email Signup

Sign up to have blog posts delivered straight to your inbox!

Topics
  • Banking and Finance
  • Constitutional Law
  • Criminal Justice
  • Defense and Foreign Policy
  • Education
  • Free Speech and Civil Liberties
  • Global Freedom
  • Government and Politics
  • Health Care
  • Immigration
  • Monetary Policy
  • Poverty and Social Welfare
  • Regulation
  • Tax and Budget Policy
  • Technology and Privacy
  • Trade Policy
Archives
  • April 2021
  • March 2021
  • February 2021
  • January 2021
  • December 2020
  • November 2020
  • October 2020
  • September 2020
  • August 2020
  • July 2020
  • June 2020
  • May 2020
  • April 2020
  • March 2020
  • February 2020
  • January 2020
  • December 2019
  • November 2019
  • October 2019
  • September 2019
  • August 2019
  • July 2019
  • June 2019
  • May 2019
  • April 2019
  • March 2019
  • February 2019
  • January 2019
  • December 2018
  • November 2018
  • October 2018
  • September 2018
  • August 2018
  • July 2018
  • June 2018
  • May 2018
  • April 2018
  • March 2018
  • February 2018
  • January 2018
  • December 2017
  • November 2017
  • October 2017
  • September 2017
  • August 2017
  • July 2017
  • June 2017
  • May 2017
  • April 2017
  • March 2017
  • February 2017
  • January 2017
  • December 2016
  • November 2016
  • October 2016
  • September 2016
  • August 2016
  • July 2016
  • June 2016
  • May 2016
  • April 2016
  • March 2016
  • February 2016
  • January 2016
  • December 2015
  • November 2015
  • October 2015
  • September 2015
  • August 2015
  • July 2015
  • June 2015
  • May 2015
  • April 2015
  • March 2015
  • February 2015
  • January 2015
  • December 2014
  • November 2014
  • October 2014
  • September 2014
  • August 2014
  • July 2014
  • June 2014
  • May 2014
  • April 2014
  • March 2014
  • February 2014
  • January 2014
  • December 2013
  • November 2013
  • October 2013
  • September 2013
  • August 2013
  • July 2013
  • June 2013
  • May 2013
  • April 2013
  • March 2013
  • February 2013
  • January 2013
  • December 2012
  • November 2012
  • October 2012
  • September 2012
  • August 2012
  • July 2012
  • June 2012
  • May 2012
  • April 2012
  • March 2012
  • February 2012
  • January 2012
  • December 2011
  • November 2011
  • October 2011
  • September 2011
  • August 2011
  • July 2011
  • June 2011
  • May 2011
  • April 2011
  • March 2011
  • February 2011
  • January 2011
  • December 2010
  • November 2010
  • October 2010
  • September 2010
  • August 2010
  • July 2010
  • June 2010
  • May 2010
  • April 2010
  • March 2010
  • February 2010
  • January 2010
  • December 2009
  • November 2009
  • October 2009
  • September 2009
  • August 2009
  • July 2009
  • June 2009
  • May 2009
  • April 2009
  • March 2009
  • February 2009
  • January 2009
  • December 2008
  • November 2008
  • October 2008
  • September 2008
  • August 2008
  • July 2008
  • June 2008
  • May 2008
  • April 2008
  • March 2008
  • February 2008
  • January 2008
  • December 2007
  • November 2007
  • October 2007
  • September 2007
  • August 2007
  • July 2007
  • June 2007
  • May 2007
  • April 2007
  • March 2007
  • February 2007
  • January 2007
  • December 2006
  • November 2006
  • October 2006
  • September 2006
  • August 2006
  • July 2006
  • June 2006
  • May 2006
  • April 2006
  • Show More
February 25, 2019 10:15AM

Why Bans Will Not Encourage “Responsible Innovation”

By Diego Zuluaga

SHARE

Two recent announcements by the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau have proponents of increased financial regulation up in arms.

The first is the Bureau’s expansion of its no-action letter policy to include a regulatory sandbox. A sandbox is a program which allows firms to offer new products under a modified regulatory regime and with oversight from financial regulators. No-action letters, for their part, are assurances from a regulator that it will not take adverse actions in response to a specific new practice by a regulated firm. Neither policy heralds the advent of a regulatory Wild West.

The second announcement involved changes to the CFPB’s payday lending rule, which in its original form (published in 2017) would have made most high-cost short-term lending of this kind unprofitable, reducing loan volumes by more than 65 percent. The Bureau’s modified rule removes an underwriting provision that would have made it very difficult for borrowers to access short-term credit, as they currently do in the 33 states where payday lending is legal. The Bureau has re-considered the costs and benefits of this provision, finding that the loss of access to credit would not be sufficiently offset by an increase in borrower well-being. This finding is bolstered by the fact that Professor Ronald Mann, author of an academic study on which the CFPB heavily relied in its original rule, strongly disavowed the Bureau’s use of his work.

In its original form, the payday rule would have banned much existing high-cost short-term credit, which typically flows to borrowers with few alternatives. Opponents of the industry, as well as some state officials, have – perhaps unsurprisingly – criticized both of the CFPB’s announcements. They ostensibly favor “responsible innovation,” without necessarily specifying what behavior warrants the “responsible” tag. They seem to view a strong stance against payday lending as fully compatible with dynamic and innovative credit markets. But this view is questionable, for three reasons.

1. Bans make it more difficult to gauge consumer demand and profitability.

The first step to innovating is identifying an explicit or latent consumer need. Sometimes innovation involves incremental improvements on an existing product – such as more powerful microchips – and other times it entails entirely new products – such as the iPhone or the retail index fund.

A key way to identify consumer need is to be able to analyze what consumers are currently doing. The CFPB estimates that as many as 12 million U.S. individuals use payday loans. These are costly products – much costlier than other forms of credit, such as credit cards, personal bank loans, and student loans, which many more Americans use. Who are payday borrowers, why are they willing to borrow at high cost, why don’t they resort to alternatives, and is it profitable to lend to them?

The availability of high-cost credit makes potential challengers – interested in offering substantively the same service at lower cost – better able to estimate whether entering the market is viable and attractive. If there are no incumbents to replace, it is more difficult to gauge the likely demand for new products, and the related profit margins. Even Henry Ford, when he invented the Model T, had two pieces of evidence to go by: the rich used fast and expensive cars, the poor used cheaper and slow horses. What was needed was an inexpensive and fast car, so he set about building one.

2. Bans increase regulatory uncertainty.

Innovating involves significant upfront investments. The innovator hopes that, if the product is successful, it will quickly become a consumer favorite, producing a stream of profits stretching into the future that will more than cover the initial outlay.

But existing bans force potential innovators to reckon with an unknown quantity: the chance that their own product, even if offering a marginal improvement over banned alternatives, might also face prohibition. This probability is hard to quantify but obviously has critical implications for the profitability of an investment. Faced with the chance of a potential ban that has regulatory precedent, many innovators will simply refrain from entering the market at all.

A recent example of the chilling effect that regulatory uncertainty can have is the 2013 “guidance” from the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) discouraging banks from offering cash advances to their depositors. Whether wittingly or unwittingly, it led banks to retreat from the market for small-dollar loans. Now, new leadership at the OCC and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation is trying to lure banks back into the business of small unsecured loans. Banks, understandably, are skeptical.

Innovation, even without regulatory meddling, involves a great deal of business uncertainty. That’s why successful innovators reap ample financial rewards. But the chance of a ban is difficult to enter into the innovator’s profit equation. It makes innovation, which is socially beneficial, privately very costly and therefore unattractive.

3. Bans give incumbents more leverage to regulate.

No ban is just the work of a do-gooder. Every prohibition in history involved an alliance – implicit or open – between people concerned about a product for moral reasons, and those who stand to benefit from the ban. Bruce Yandle dubbed this confluence of interests “bootleggers and Baptists.”

Many people stand to profit from a ban on high-cost credit. In particularly stringent jurisdictions, a credit ban will drive people in need to loan sharks. In other places, borrowers will resort to pawn shops, which also charge high implicit prices and require customers to leave prized possessions behind. For those borrowers lucky enough to have access to other forms of credit, the unavailability of products such as payday loans can mean increased overdraft charges. In other words, borrowers will pay the cost of a ban, but other lenders will benefit from the absence of competition.

That opportunity for rent extraction creates strong incentives to support a ban. Incumbents will expend resources to try and persuade policymakers not only of the wisdom of the ban, but of the danger involved in allowing any new innovation. Bans make innovation less rewarding and political maneuvering more attractive.

Proponents of credit bans, among them church groups, community groups, and progressive politicians, seem to divide the world into one of “responsible” lenders and innovators, who should be allowed to operate, and “irresponsible” characters who must be driven out. This Manichaean view of the credit landscape may reassure its adherents that they’re doing God’s work. But it does a scant favor to borrowers who willingly use the products that prohibitionists wish to ban, usually because it’s their best available alternative.

Recent experience suggests that an enthusiastically interventionist stance doesn’t work. The CFPB’s previous attempt to encourage innovation, dubbed “Project Catalyst,” failed because the Bureau didn’t offer sufficient assurance that it wouldn’t come after innovators once they’d launched a new product. The original payday lending rule, for its part, aroused not just forceful opposition from lenders, but a livid response from an academic who saw his work misused to justify a draconian regulation.

Anti-payday loan activists claim to be defending hard-pressed borrowers from abuse. Yet, foreclosing access to the few options these people have is not a responsible approach. Instead, policy should encourage an environment in which more firms can offer borrowers more and better products without fear or favor. Calls for bans, or effective bans like the old payday rule, coupled with vague promises that a “responsible” lender will eventually emerge, amount to mere grandstanding.

[Cross-posted from Alt-M.org]

Stay Connected to Cato

Sign up for the newsletter to receive periodic updates on Cato research, events, and publications.

View All Newsletters

1000 Massachusetts Ave. NW
Washington, DC 20001-5403
202-842-0200
Contact Us
Privacy

Footer 1

  • About
    • Annual Reports
    • Leadership
    • Jobs
    • Student Programs
    • Media Information
    • Store
    • Contact
  • Podcasts

Footer 2

  • Experts
    • Policy Scholars
    • Adjunct Scholars
    • Fellows
  • Events
    • Upcoming
    • Past
    • Event FAQs
    • Sphere Summit

Footer 3

  • Publications
    • Books
    • Cato Journal
    • Regulation
    • Cato Policy Report
    • Cato Supreme Court Review
    • Cato’s Letter
    • Human Freedom Index
    • Economic Freedom of the World
    • Cato Handbook for Policymakers

Footer 4

  • Blog
  • Donate
    • Sponsorship Benefits
    • Ways to Give
    • Planned Giving
Also from Cato Institute:
Libertarianism.org
|
Humanprogress.org
|
Downsizinggovernment.org