The International Monetary Fund has grown in resources and responsibilities since it was established in 1944. It has become abundantly clear that the IMF’s “original rationale no longer fits,“1 that the world economy has changed dramatically since the fund was established, and that the increasing frequency and severity of economic crises in recent years require a rethinking of the IMF’s role in the global financial system.

The IMF has recognized this need and is introducing some reforms to the way it operates. The fund has in fact developed new missions for itself many times in response to crises or changes in the world economy. Those episodes have included the end of the system of fixed exchange rates in the early 1970s, the subsequent oil crises of that decade, the Third World debt crisis of the 1980s, the collapse of socialism, and, beginning with Mexico in 1994, emerging market financial crises.

In short, the IMF has expanded its role from providing short-term loans based on macroeconomic policy change to providing longer-term aid conditioned on structural economic reforms to providing bailout funds and becoming an international crisis manager. As the graph shows, new missions and greater lending have led to periodic increases in the fund’s resources, which donor nations have granted every time such increases have been requested.


Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); and IMF, Financial Organization and Operations of the IMF(Washington: IMF, 1990).

The IMF today finds itself in an awkward position. It continues to provide massive aid to countries suffering from financial crises while wishing to avoid creating moral hazard. The agency has thus proposed initiatives to “bail in” the private sector, so as to make investors bear more of the cost of bad investment decisions. Conversely, the fund has created a line of credit to provide aid to countries before crises occur, so as to prevent them. Yet preventive lines of credit are likely to increase moral hazard, while efforts to force losses on the private sector may precipitate the very crises they intend to prevent. Finally, the IMF wishes to become more transparent and improve its surveillance function. Its dual goals of preventing the outbreak of financial turmoil and maintaining relations with client countries, however, may undermine the fund’s credibility.

Many of the problems the IMF seeks to resolve would be reduced or eliminated with increased reliance on direct negotiations between lenders and borrowers in international finance and decreased reliance on IMF lending and mediation. That has become more and more evident since the early 1980s. To see why, it is useful to look at the evolution of the IMF.

Early Years

The International Monetary Fund was established at Bretton Woods in the aftermath of the Great Depression and at the end of World War II, when confidence in a liberal world economy was low. The fund’s purpose was to maintain exchange rate stability by lending to countries experiencing temporary balance of payments problems. In a world of fixed exchange rates, countries would only be allowed to alter their exchange rates if there were fundamental imbalances in their economies. In this way, the IMF would promote international stability and avert competitive devaluations.

Although world trade did increase under the Bretton Woods system, trade did not return to its 1913 level (as a share of the global economy) until the mid-1970s, after the Bretton Woods system was abandoned. Moreover, the system was not as orderly as envisioned by its founders. Sharp and sudden currency devaluations would occur. Economic historian Leland Yeager observed that “The authorities of a country desiring to change its exchange rate typically make up their own minds on the matter and then simply notify the Fund. Though this notification is phrased as a request for permission, the Fund actually faces the choice only between acquiescing or risking loss of face by seeing its authority flouted and the change made anyway.“2

The Bretton Woods system was, in fact, “unworkable from the start” and “promptly began to break down” once major European countries began lifting capital controls on their currencies in 1958.3 The breakdown occurred because countries pursued a combination of unsustainable policies—free capital flows, fixed exhange rates, and independent monetary policies. By the time President Nixon finally abandoned this system in 1971, thus ending the international system of fixed exchange rates, he was merely acknowledging economic reality. That similar scenario has been played out in the 1990s as financial crises have forced developing countries to learn that they cannot pursue both independent monetary policies and tie their currencies to the dollar in a world of free capital flows. It is somewhat ironic then, that the recent financial crises in Asia and elsewhere have elicited calls for the establishment of a “new Bretton Woods.”

The Post-Bretton Woods Era

The collapse of the system of fixed exchange rates managed by the fund ended the IMF’s original mission. Lending by the fund, nevertheless, doubled from 1970 to 1975. The oil crises of that decade led the IMF to create oil facilities, or new lending mechanisms that would make it easier for countries to cope with the rising cost of oil imports. (In the event, Great Britain and Italy became the largest users of that credit line.)4 In creating the new credit window, the fund was going beyond its usual lending activities but was following a pattern it had begun in the 1960s, when it established two other credit facilities intended to help countries cope with swings in commodity prices.5 By 1975, the IMF launched the Extended Fund Facility, which would provide credit, mainly to developing countries, on more lenient terms than those available through standard IMF programs. The fund has since created a host of credit programs that provide increasingly concessional loans. Observers noted that the IMF was taking on functions more appropriate to a foreign aid agency like the World Bank than to an international monetary institution.

The outbreak of the Third World debt crisis in 1982 initiated the era of international financial rescues led by the IMF. In the post-World War II era, threats to the international financial system that were considered systemic had not yet erupted. While previous to the founding of the IMF, debt crises in poor countries involved little or no official mediation, authorities now ruled out direct negotiations between debtor countries and creditors as unrealistic. The largest U.S. money-center banks had made sovereign loans that exceeded their capital. Most banks were eager for the IMF to provide funding, as were Third World countries that wished to avoid default and gain access to easier credit.

Thus, developed countries initially responded to the possibility of a Third World debt default by treating it as liquidity problem and providing new loans directly and through multilateral agencies. As part of the deal, commercial banks were to continue lending. In the early stages, IMF loans did not necessarily require structural adjustment since authorities believed that indebted nations needed some time to get their finances in order. Under IMF programs, countries thus raised taxes and tariffs and reduced government expenditures. By 1985, it had become obvious that deep-rooted problems in developing country economies were preventing them from growing out of their debt. A new strategy was then announced by U.S Treasury Secretary James A. Baker whereby new money from the IMF and commercial banks would be based on market reforms. In exchange for that money, indebted countries were to liberalize their economies.

By 1987, it became evident that that strategy was not working. Countries did very little in the way of economic reform, though they continued to receive funding. Banks, though they continued to lend, were reducing their exposure in the region. A slow transfer of private debt to public debt was occurring in the absence of a resolution to the underlying problems that caused the debt crisis.6

IMF conditionality appeared to provide little incentive to reform. Sebastian Edwards, formerly the World Bank’s chief economist for Latin America, referred to the IMF as “participating in a big charade,” because fund programs imply that “there is a high probability that the country will attain balance-of-payment viability in the near future. For many countries this is not the case and everybody knows it.“7

By financing governments that were uninterested in serious liberalization and structural adjustment, the Fund actually delayed reforms in Latin America during the 1980s. Latin America became more indebted, private commercial banks in the United States were able to postpone recognizing losses, and the living standards of Latin Americans fell. MIT economist Rudi Dornbusch noted that “The IMF set itself up to save the system, organizing banks into a lender’s cartel and holding the debtor countries up for a classical mugging.“8 As Anna Schwartz commented in her 1988 presidential address to the Western Economics Association, “the intervention of the official players has prolonged and worsened the debt problem.“9 Peter Lindert found that as a result of IMF intervention, “Most [debtor nations] have participated in a three-party stalemate, in which official agencies, private creditors, and debtor countries agree, after repeated struggles and much uncertainty, to reschedule in a way that postpones large net resource flows.“10

The end of the 1980s and beginning of the 1990s finally did see the introduction of far-reaching market reforms, a development for which the IMF often takes credit. But that outcome resulted from economic necessity in the wake of the collapse of development planning and of other failed economic policies. By the end of the 1980s, the banks ultimately opted for a solution that some prominent figures in the financial community had recommended early on: banks set aside loan-loss reserves and wrote down the value of their loans. If banks were indeed threatened by the Third World debt situation, they could have borrowed directly from the U.S. Federal Reserve Board at a penalty. It was always questionable for the IMF to attempt replicating the role of a lender of last resort. For that reason, the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis has recently noted that “the IMF is redundant to prevent worldwide financial crises,” and “should cease its lending activities altogether.“11

The IMF’s move in the opposite direction probably contributed to creating the lost decade of the 1980s. As economists Lindert and Peter Morton noted in 1987, “the intervention of the Fund and the [World] Bank has impeded the striking of bilateral bargains between debtor governments and the creditor banks.“12 Shortly before joining the IMF, MIT professor Stanley Fischer expressed apparent agreement with that assessment: “I believe that the debt crisis would have been over sooner had the official agencies not been involved.” Fischer added, however, that he thought that in the absence of official intervention the adjustment crisis would have been deeper.13But it is hard to imagine that Latin America would have suffered more had the liberal reforms that were eventually introduced in the late 1980s and early 1990s been implemented seven or eight years earlier.

Recent History

With the collapse of socialism, IMF lending again began to rise and has shot up significantly after the fall of the Mexican peso in 1994 (see graph). The fund thus took on the role of turning formerly socialist countries from central planning to the market. The creation of a

new Systemic Transformation Facility in 1993, through which countries like Russia would borrow on easier terms than available under standard IMF programs, exemplified the fund’s new initiative. The Mexican peso crisis of 1994–95 initiated a new era of massive emergency lending by the IMF to countries experiencing financial crises.

In fact, there have been at least 90 severe banking crises in the developing world since 1982 and the losses in 20 of those cases have ranged between 10 and 25 percent of GDP.14 A number of flawed policies in the countries experiencing those banking problems are, of course, to blame for creating such financial disasters. Principal among those policies is the explicit or implicit guarantee by developing country governments that they will rescue domestic banks if they get into trouble. The result has been the creation of moral hazard at the national level. The more governments rescue unhealthy banks and their business associates, the riskier we can expect banks to behave.

The IMF has complicated the situation by adding moral hazard at the international level. When the Mexican peso fell in 1994 as a result of expansionary fiscal and monetary policies that were inconsistent with its pegged exchange rate, moral hazard was already well established. In 1995 the IMF and the U.S. Treasury decided, for the fourth time in 20 years, to rescue the Mexican government and investors from the consequences of irresponsible election year policies.15 The bailout allowed Mexico to repay in full about $25 billion worth of dollar indexed bonds. Those investors suffered no risk or losses but were able to pass the bill on to ordinary Mexicans in the form of greater debt. The redistribution of wealth from the relatively poor to the relatively well off has been a feature of subsequent bailouts. The U.S. Treasury and the fund have claimed Mexico a success, but the intervention there sent a signal to the world that if anything went wrong in emerging economies, the IMF would come to investors’ rescue.

Moral hazard helps explain the doubling of capital flows to East Asia in 1995 alone. Governments that have received emergency IMF aid since then were not discouraged from maintaining flawed policies as long as lenders kept the capital flowing—which lenders imprudently did with the knowledge that official aid would be used in case of financial troubles.

To be sure, the financial crises in Mexico, Asia, Russia and Brazil were not necessarily created by the IMF; rather, they were a product of poor domestic policies to which IMF lending contributed. (In Asia, those policies included borrowing in foreign currencies and lending in domestic currency under pegged exchange rates; extensively borrowing in the short term and lending in the long term; lack of supervision of borrowers’ balance sheets by foreign lenders; and shaky financial systems. Mexico, Russia and Brazil shared many of those misguided policies plus unsustainable fiscal deficits.)

IMF interventions in crisis countries have been justified on the grounds that fund conditionality promotes market reforms and that emergency lending helps avert systemic threats to the international economy. Yet the impact of conditionality is at best ambiguous and has clearly not worked in Russia since 1992 or Indonesia since 1997. Moreover, the record of IMF lending does not speak well either of the temporary nature of IMF loans or of IMF conditionality—70 countries have depended on IMF credit for 20 or more years. (See Appendices A and B).16 As the graph below shows, once a county receives IMFcredit, it is likely to become dependent on fund aid for most, if not all, of the following years.

Major factors undermining the effectiveness of the fund are its inability to enforce loan conditions and its institutional incentive to lend. Especially when it lends to governments uninterested in reforms, the fund’s credit does little to promote policy or structural changes. In such cases, the fund suspends credit until it receives promises or evidence of policy change in the right direction. At that point, the fund releases credit again taking the pressure off of the recipient government to reform. Indeed, the fund cannot afford to watch a country reform on its own without the IMF’s involvement. That scenario has occurred numerous times in post-Soviet Russia, certainly delaying the country’s transition to the market. It has also prompted leading Russian liberals to denounce IMF aid to Moscow. In a July 1999 letter to IMF managing director Michel Camdessus, for example, former Russian Deputy Prime Minister Boris Federov warned against a new loan to Russia, which was subsequently approved: “I strongly believe that IMF money injections in 1994–1998were detrimental to the Russian economy and interests of the Russian people. Instead of speeding up reforms, they slowed them.“17

The fund’s incentive to lend is well known both by the fund and by recipient governments, thus making the fund’s conditionality much less credible. Even in Asia, where some countries show signs of economic improvement, the record is ambiguous. As The Economist magazine recently pointed out, the recovery there reflects “the natural propensity of economies to bounce back.… What it does not reflect is fundamental, structural reform, in any country in the region.“18

Have recent events supported the case for official intervention on the grounds that IMF aid is necessary to resolve financial crises and avert contagion? Only after Brazil’s currency crisis—two months after the IMF bailout—did the government there take tentative steps to address the country’s problems. The collapse of the Russian ruble in August 1998 and subsequent debt default—which an IMF bailout did not prevent—rattled world markets and likely reduced moral hazard. Successive interest rate cuts by the Federal Reserve and other central banks then helped calm world markets, raising questions about the utility of the IMF in both preventing defaults and dealing with their global effects. Indeed, the Brazilian devaluation did not have the colossal consequences that the IMF and U.S. Treasury predicted, probably in large part due to the effects of the Russian crisis.

Market discipline has also been at work in Korea. As Jeffrey Sachs notes, the fund responded to the Korean crisis by providing a tranche of credit in late 1997, but “The Korean debacle ended only when Korea ran out of IMF money, forcing the international bank creditors to agree to roll over the debts owed by Korean banks.“19Even so, the restructuring was “far from ideal” since the newly restructured debt was generously guaranteed by the Korean government at higher interest rates than that of the original debts.20

Morris Goldstein also questions the IMF approach in Korea. According to him, it is not “clear that the first round of rollovers that did take place … would not have happened anyway in the absence of a promise of accelerated disbursements from the official sector. The argument that creditors are too numerous and dispersed to make such discussions feasible did not seem to apply in this case. If the rescue package for South Korea were smaller … and disbursements were not accelerated, a larger amount would have had to be rescheduled.” Moreover, losses in Korea would not have made Western banks insolvent.21

Where We Are Now

Recent experience has prompted initiatives at the fund to improve its transparency and its surveillance function, do more to prevent financial crises from erupting, and find ways to “bail in” the private sector. The IMF’s role as a surveillance agency has been seriously tarnished by the Asian crisis. The fund provided no warning about the impending collapse of currencies and domestic banking systems and instead lauded the East Asian economies in public documents shortly before the outbreak of the crises. The financial community has not been comforted by the fund’s claims that the governments it was dealing with were not transparent (which would amount to an admission that the fund did not fully know what was going on) and that the agency did in fact provide warnings to officials in Thailand but kept that information confidential. That episode only highlights an inherent conflict in the fund’s role as both a credit rating agency for countries and an agency that attempts to prevent the eruption of financial turmoil. For if the IMF did detect alarming economic conditions in an emerging economy, the public release of that information would precipitate a crisis; not sounding the alarms, however, would further undermine the IMF’s credibility as a surveillance agency. As long as the IMF pretends to maintain both roles, that conflict will continue to exist.22

The IMF has also established a new facility this year to provide bailout funds beforecountries experience financial difficulties in an effort to prevent them. The Contingent Credit Lines (CCL) program is intended to serve as “a precautionary line of defense“23 that would stave off creditor panics in countries with fundamentally sound economies. But the fund has not shown good judgment in determining what countries would benefit from preventive bailouts. The two times the fund has provided such aid—Russia (July 1998) and Brazil (November 1998)—the bailouts failed to prevent currency devaluations and financial crises. Such funds merely became gifts to speculators and financial institutions, leaving both countries in greater debt.

The CCL, moreover, is based on the dubious assumption that countries with sound economic fundamentals are subject to contagion. It is difficult to find a country, however, that has succumbed to crisis that did not also already have severe domestic economic problems. Every country that has experienced financial turmoil has had fundamentally flawed economic policies. Systemic crisis has not spread to countries with sound economic fundamentals. Had the CCL existed since 1997, it is not clear which country it would have saved. The CCL is likely to expand moral hazard without providing any tangible benefits.

Finally, the IMF has reacted to criticisms that its lending has created moral hazard by exploring ways to make private-sector lenders bear more of a burden when resolving financial crises. Naturally, private sector creditors object to any moves by the IMF that would encourage debtor countries not to meet their debt obligations in full and on time. The fund practice of reducing debt by lending to countries that have not yet completed debt renegotiations with their private sector creditors would essentially force losses on private lenders who have so far benefited from bailouts. Yet any such initiatives carry a high risk. Official efforts to bail in the private sector may precipitate the financial turmoil they were designed to prevent since lenders would have an incentive to pull out of a country whenever they sensed that international authorities will force losses on them.24

More Flexibility Is Needed

There is a better approach to reduce moral hazard and prevent crises from occurring that avoids the conflicts the IMF now faces. When crises occur, direct negotiations between creditors and debtors as an alternative to IMF lending and mediation would lead to an automatic “bailing in” of the private sector. Indeed, private creditors would already be bailed in and have every incentive to renegotiate debts, perhaps including a certain amount of debt forgiveness, as would developing country debtors have every incentive to reach a reasonable agreement with creditors as quickly as possible. Recent and historical experience shows that direct creditor-debtor bargains have often overcome problems of coordination, information and insurance to both deal with financial turmoil when it erupts and to help prevent it.25 In the 19th and 20th centuries, bondholder committees, banking clubs and banking syndicates have formed to provide those so-called public goods upon which much IMF lending is now justified.

As University of Chicago economist Randall Kroszner has noted, in the new international financial architecture, less is more. Less bailout capacity and less inflexibility on the part of creditors can produce a more stable global financial system.26 Less fund involvement would also produce more market innovations that are currently precluded by official interventions. Standby lines of credit could be provided by banks to countries in the case that they be negatively affected by outside shocks. Since banks would not provide such a service to all countries, the very provision of such loans would increase investor confidence and (unlike the case of IMF lending) serve as useful signal to the markets as to which countries can be expected to have more sound economic fundamentals in place.

The market for credit risk insurance and restructuring insurance could also develop to meet the needs of market participants’ diverse tastes for risk. The severity of financial turmoil would thus be reduced because not all investors would behave the same way in times of crisis.27 In the case of sovereign bonds, contracts could include clauses concerning majority voting or workout procedures in the event of default. Again, official lending has made that outcome less probable. Even so, since the 1980s, there have been several cases of successful voluntary sovereign bond restructurings that have overcome problems requiring the unanimous consent of bondholders.28

Relying more on debtors and creditors to resolve and prevent financial crises would reduce moral hazard, increase the quality of surveillance, and lead to innovations that would reduce the severity of crises. Private creditors would be responsible for bearing the full consequences of their investment decisions, a system of real conditionality and real reform would evolve, and the parties involved would have no incentive to stall the process of debt resolution. Taking an approach based on direct creditor-debtor bargains requires that countries be allowed to default. The very possibility of default would, in many cases, help lead to debt renegotiations, thus improving the position of both debtors and creditors. As Koszner puts it, “it may indeed be better to forgive than to receive. Asking for less can result in receiving more while also making the distressed country better off.“29 Default itself need not be traumatic. Indeed, history shows that defaults have repeatedly occurred, but they have usually been partial rather than complete and lending often resumes soon after the defaults. In short, relying on direct creditor-debtor negotiations would eliminate many of the conflicts now facing the IMF.

Conclusion

The world economy has changed dramatically since the creation of the IMF. The fund long ago lost its original mission but has taken on new functions since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system. The rise of IMF lending and crisis mediation since the early 1980s reflects, in large part, the development of a dysfunctional relationship between lenders and borrowers in international finance. Repairing that relationship requires that moral hazard be reduced and that crisis prevention and management be more effective. The IMF’s new initiatives to deal with crises, however, are likely to be ineffective. An approach based on greater reliance on two-party negotiations holds more promise in stabilizing the international financial system than the current approach, in which the IMF too often becomes a burdensome third party.




Appendix A

Use of IMF Credit by Eligible Countries, 1947–99 

Country First Year Used Number of Years Used Percentage of Years Used after Year of First Use

Africa

Algeria

1989

11

100.00

Benin

1978

22

100.00

Burkina Faso

1978

22

100.00

Burundi

1968

29

90.63

Cameroon

1974

26

100.00

Central African Republic

1974

26

100.00

Chad

1970

30

100.00

Congo, Dem. Republic

1972

28

100.00

Congo, Rep. Of

1977

23

100.00

Equatorial Guinea

1980

20

100.00

Ethiopia

1949

22

43.14

Gabon

1978

20

90.91

Gambia

1977

23

100.00

Ghana

1962

35

92.11

Guinea

1969

31

100.00

Guinea-Bissau

1979

21

100.00

Ivory Coast

1974

26

100.00

Kenya

1974

26

100.00

Lesotho

1977

23

100.00

Liberia

1963

33

89.19

Madagascar

1974

26

100.00

Malawi

1975

25

100.00

Mali

1964

35

97.22

Mauritania

1976

24

100.00

Mauritius

1969

15

48.39

Morocco

1968

24

75.00

Mozambique

1987

13

100.00

Niger

1983

22

100.00

Rwanda

1966

26

76.47

Sao Tome and Principe

1989

11

100.00

Senegal

1975

25

100.00

Sierra Leone

1967

29

87.88

Somalia

1964

26

72.22

South Africa

1976

15

62.50

Sudan

1958

39

92.86

Swaziland

1979

12

57.14

Tanzania

1974

26

100.00

Togo

1976

24

100.00

Tunisia

1964

25

69.44

Uganda

1971

29

100.00

Zambia

1971

29

100.00

Zimbabwe

1981

18

94.74


Use of IMF Credit by Eligible Countries, 1947–99 (continued)

Asia

Afghanistan

1964

13

36.11

Bangladesh

1972

28

100.00

Cambodia

1972

28

100.00

China

1981

10

52.63

Fiji

1974

12

46.15

India

1949

44

86.27

Indonesia

1956

29

65.91

Laos

1975

25

100.00

Malaysia

1976

7

29.17

Mongolia

1991

9

100.00

Myanmar

1967

24

72.73

Nepal

1976

24

100.00

Pakistan

1965

35

100.00

Papua New Guinea

1976

24

100.00

Philippines

1955

39

86.67

South Korea

1974

17

65.38

Salomon Islands

1981

10

52.63

Sri Lanka

1961

39

100.00

Thailand

1976

18

75.00

Vietnam

1977

23

100.00

Western Samoa

1975

17

68.00


Europe

Albania

1992

8

100.00

Armenia

1994

6

100.00

Azerbaijan

1995

5

100.00

Belarus

1993

7

100.00

Bosnia and Herzegovina

1995

5

100.00

Bulgaria

1991

9

100.00

Croatia

1993

7

100.00

Cyprus

1974

11

42.31

Czech Republic

1993

1

14.29

Czechoslovakia

1990

3

100.00

Estonia

1992

8

100.00

Georgia

1994

6

100.00

Hungary

1982

16

88.89

Kazakhstan

1993

7

100.00

Kyrgyz Republic

1993

7

100.00

Latvia

1992

8

100.00

Lithuania

1992

8

100.00

Macedonia, FYR

1993

7

100.00

Moldova

1993

7

100.00

Poland

1990

5

50.00

Romania

1973

25

92.59

Russia

1992

8

100.00

Slovak Republic

1993

7

100.00

Slovenia

1993

4

57.14

Turkey

1953

40

85.11

Ukraine
1994
6
100.00

Uzbekistan

1995

5

100.00

Yugoslavia

1949

41

93.18


Use of IMF Credit by Eligible Countries, 1947–99 (continued)

Middle East

Egypt

1957

40

93.02

Iran

1955

6

13.33

Iraq

1967

2

6.06

Israel

1957

18

41.86

Jordan

1971

22

75.86

Syria

1960

16

40.00

Yemen Arab Republic

1983

5

71.43

Yemen People’s Dem. Rep.

1974

16

100.00

Republic of Yemen

1990

5

50.00


Western Hemisphere

Argentina

1957

33

76.74

Barbados

1977

19

82.61

Belize

1983

8

47.06

Bolivia

1959

35

85.37

Brazil

1951

33

67.35

Chile

1957

38

88.37

Colombia

1954

16

34.78

Costa Rica

1961

30

76.92

Dominica

1979

20

95.24

Dominican Republic

1960

36

90.00

Ecuador

1957

29

67.44

El Salvador

1956

23

52.27

Grenada

1975

16

64.00

Guatemala

1962

18

47.37

Guyana

1971

27

93.10

Haiti

1958

39

92.86

Honduras

1957

33

76.74

Jamaica

1973

27

100.00

Mexico

1976

22

91.67

Nicaragua

1957

33

76.74

Panama

1968

28

87.50

Paraguay

1956

5

11.36

Peru

1958

31

73.81

St. Lucia

1980

6

30.00

St. Vincent

1980

6

30.00

Trinidad and Tobago

1988

10

83.33

Uruguay

1962

32

84.21

Venezuela

1989

11

100.00

Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues).

Note: This table includes outstanding use of the IMF’s credits within the General Resources Account, Structural Adjustment Facility,

Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility, and Trust Fund loans. Data for Yugoslavia to 1992; data for Czechoslovakia to 1993; data for Yemen Arab Republic and Yemen People’s Democratic Republic to 1990. 

Appendix B

Use of IMF Credit, 1949–99

40 Years or More (4)

Egypt, India, Turkey, Yugoslavia

30 to 39 Years (20)

Costa Rica, Chad, Peru, Guinea, Uruguay, Brazil, Argentina, Honduras, Nicaragua, Liberia, Bolivia, Ghana, Mali, Pakistan, Dominican Republic, Chile, Philippines, Sudan, Haiti, Sri Lanka

20 to 29 Years (46)

Gabon, Dominica, Equatorial Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Ethiopia, Jordan, Mexico, Benin, Burkina Faso, Niger, El Salvador, Congo, Rep. Of, Gambia, Lesotho, Vietnam, Myanmar, Morocco, Mauritania, Togo, Nepal, Papua New Guinea, Tunisia, Romania, Malawi, Senegal, Laos, Somalia, Rwanda, Cameroon, Central African Republic, Ivory Coast, Kenya, Madagascar, Tanzania, Guyana, Jamaica, Panama, Congo, Dem. Republic, Bangladesh, Cambodia, Indonesia, Ecuador, Sierra Leone, Burundi, Uganda, Zambia

10 to 19 Years (25)

China, Salomon Islands, Trinidad and Tobago, Cyprus, Algeria, Sao Tome and Principe, Venezuela, Fiji, Swaziland, Afghanistan, Mozambique, Mauritius, South Africa, Colombia, Syria, Grenada, Hungary, Yemen People’s Dem. Rep., South Korea, Western Samoa, Israel, Guatemala, Thailand, Zimbabwe, Barbados

Less than 10 Years (29)

Czech Republic, Iraq, Slovenia, Paraguay, Poland, Republic of Yemen, Yemen Arab Republic, Iran, St. Lucia, St. Vincent, Armenia, Georgia, Ukraine, Malaysia, Belarus, Croatia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Macedonia, FYR, Moldova, Slovak Republic, Belize, Albania, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Russia, Mongolia, Bulgaria

NOTES:
1. Anne O. Krueger, “Wither the World Bank and the IMF?” Journal of Economic Literature, December 1998, vol. 36, p. 1983.

2. Leland B. Yeager, International Monetary Relations: Theory, History, and Policy (New York: Harper and Row, 1966, 1976), p. 403.

3. Francis Gavin, “The Legends of Bretton Woods,” Orbis, Spring 1996, p. 185 and “Bretton Woods: A Not So Golden Era,” paper presented at the Cato Institute conference, “The Crisis In Global Interventionism,” June 10, 1999. Additionally, Raymond Mikesell points out that “the Fund remained largely irrelevant for the first fifteen years of its existence.” See Raymond Mikesell, “The Bretton Woods Debates: A Memoir,” Princeton Essays in International Finance no. 192, March 1994, p. 60.

4. Pedro-Pablo Kuczynski, Latin American Debt (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1988), p. 41.

5. Those credit windows were the Compensatory Financing Facility established in 1963 and the Buffer Stock Financing Facility in 1969.

6. Paul Krugman calculated that from 1982 to 1987, the stock of official creditor loans to the Baker plan countries increased from $50 billion to $120 billion, while that of bank loans remained at $250 billion during that time, then fell to $225 billion in 1988. Paul Krugman, “LDC Debt Policy,” in Martin Feldstein, ed., American Economic Policy in the 1980s (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994), p. 700.

7. Sebastian Edwards, “The International Monetary Fund and the Developing Countries: A Critical Evaluation,” in Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, eds., IMF Policy Advice, Market Volatility, Commodity Price Rules and Other Essays (Amsterdam: North Holland, Autumn 1989), Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, p. 39.

8. See Rudiger Dornbusch, Dollars, Debts and Deficits (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 1986), p. 140.

9. Anna J. Schwartz, “International Debts: What’s Fact and What’s Fiction?” Economic Inquiry, vol. 27, no. 1, January 1989, p. 4.

10. Peter H. Lindert, “Response to Debt Crisis: What is Different About the 1980s?” in Barry Eichengreen and Peter H. Lindert, eds., The International Debt Crisis in Historical Perspective(Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990), pp. 250–51.

11. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1998 Annual Report: Asking the Right Questions About the IMF (Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, May 1999), pp. 3 and 6.

12. Peter H. Lindert and Peter J. Morton, “How Sovereign Debt Has Worked,” in Jeffrey D. Sachs, ed.,Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1987), p. 75.

13. Stanley Fischer, “The Mission of the Fund,” in Bretton Woods: Looking to the Future(Washington: Bretton Woods Commission, 1994), p. C‑169.

14. Charles W. Calomiris, “The IMF’s Imprudent Role As Lender of Last Resort,” Cato Journal, vol. 7, no. 3, Winter 1998, pp. 280–81.

15. W. Lee Hoskins and James W. Coons, “Mexico: Policy Failure, Moral Hazard, and Market Solutions,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 243, October 10, 1995.

16. International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics (Washington: IMF, various issues).

17. Letter to Michel Camdessus from Boris Federov, July 9, 1999 (emphasis in original). A copy of the letter is in the author’s possesion. See also Boris Fyodorov, “Loans to Russia? A Russian ‘Nyet’,” Washington Post, July 22, 1999, p. A19; and Grigory A. Yavlinsky, “Western Aid Is No Help,” New York Times, July 28, 1993, p. A19.

18. “Asia’s Bounce-Back,” The Economist, August 21, 1999, p. 11.

19. Jeffrey Sachs, “Stop Preaching,” Financial Times, November 5, 1998.

20. Steven Radelet and Jeffrey Sachs, “What Have We Learned So Far From the Asian Financial Crisis?” manuscript, January 4, 1999, p. 16.

21. Morris Goldstein, The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic Implications(Washington: Institute For International Economics, 1998), p. 43.

22. An additional problem is that the Fund faces a conflict of interest since in many cases it would be evaluating a country in which it has its own money at stake

23. International Monetary Fund, “IMF Tightens Defenses Against Financial Contagion by Establishing Contingent Credit Lines,” Press Release no. 99/14, April 25, 1999.

24. See Barry Eichengreen, “Is Greater Private Sector Burden Sharing Impossible?” Finance & Development, September 1999.

25. Roland Vaubel, “The Moral Hazard of IMF Lending,” World Economy, September 1983 and Walker F. Todd, “A History of International Lending,” in George Kaufmann, ed., Research in Financial Services, (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1991), vol. 3.

26. Randall S. Kroszner, “Less Is More in the New International Financial Architecture,” in William C. Hunter, George G. Kaufmann, and Thomas H. Krueger, eds., The Asian Financial Crisis: Originis, Implications, and Solutions (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1999), p. 447.

27. Catherine L. Mann, “Market Mechanisms to Reduce the Need For IMF Bailouts,” Institute for International Economics, Policy Brief no. 99–4, February 1999.

28. Marco A. Piñon-Farah, “Private Bond Restructurings: Lessons for the Case of Sovereign Debtors,” IMF Working Paper 96/11, February 1996.

29. Kroszner, p. 451.