A typical penny auction works as follows: A valuable item is put up for auction at an attractive starting price. A countdown timer demarcates the tentative end point of the auction. A participant may press a button at any time to increase the auction price by a penny and become the high bidder. If he does so, the participant is then charged a nonrefundable bid fee, typically between 50¢ and $1. The fee is charged every time a bid is placed, and time is added to the clock if a bid is placed in the last few seconds of the auction. When time runs out, the high bidder wins the item and pays the end auction price (plus accrued transaction fees), which often is a fraction of the item’s value. Losing bidders likewise pay their transaction fees.
Regulation
To date, the penny auction industry is not subject to any special regulations, but it is subject to substantial regulatory uncertainty. The industry has recently drawn the attention of regulators such as the Federal Trade Commission, Securities and Exchange Commission, the United Kingdom’s Office of Fair Trading, Connecticut’s Department of Consumer Protection, and Washington State’s Office of the Attorney General. Major penny auction websites have also been the subject of numerous private lawsuits, the outcome of which could potentially shape how the auctions are classified under existing law.
Criticisms of penny auctions can generally be grouped into three categories: accusations that the auctions are a form of illegal gambling, complaints about deceptive advertising practices, and allegations that certain websites utilize computerized shill bidders (i.e., fake auction participants that artificially increase prices). Concerning the latter two categories, deceptive advertising and known cases of shill bidding by some websites have given the industry a black eye, but those problems are not unique to the penny auction industry and can be dealt with largely through existing channels. For example, the Better Business Bureau tracks and rates the major industry players, several of which have earned high marks. The auction websites also submit to periodic third-party audits, in part to alleviate concerns about shill bidding. Consumers can file complaints with the Better Business Bureau or the Federal Trade Commission if they encounter unfair or illegal business practices. Both entities have issued warnings to consumers about penny auction scam websites. Furthermore, in the United States and the UK, shill bidders have been successfully sued for unlawful business practices and fraud.
Putting aside the concerns about deceptive practices and shill bidders, this article examines the question of whether penny auctions are a form of gambling and should be regulated as such. As part of that examination, I present the results of an economic experiment that tested whether the behavior of auction participants, rather than their proclivity to gamble, can explain high penny auction revenues. If behavior alone can explain the high revenues, then that suggests the auctions should not be regulated like gambling.
Illegal Gambling? The Case for and against
The legal definition of gambling requires the game in question to have a prize, chance, and consideration. Some laws also pertain to bets or wagers. Penny auctions clearly have a prize (the item) and consideration (the fees collected by the website); the debate centers around whether penny auctions involve chance, bets, or wagers. Opponents argue that bids in a penny auction constitute bets that no further bids will be placed. If winning a penny auction mainly requires chance rather than skill, then penny auctions could be classified as a form of illegal gambling.
To date, regulators and industry watchdogs have stopped short of explicitly mentioning gambling in reference to penny auctions, but the similarities have been pointed out in warnings issued to consumers. According to the Federal Trade Commission,
In many ways, a penny auction is more like a lottery than a traditional online auction. In a penny auction, you have to pay to bid. Before you know it, you could spend far more than you intended, with no guarantee that you’ll get anything in return.
According to the Better Business Bureau, “Unlike typical auctions, unsuccessfully bidding on an item through a penny auction will still cost you, and [the Better Business Bureau] has heard from people who lost thousands of dollars bidding on items and have nothing to show for it.”
U.S. courts have yet to establish a precedent regarding the classification of penny auctions. To date, all cases that allege gambling have either been settled or dismissed without explanation.
There is also debate in the academic community as to whether the high revenues of penny auctions are the result of inexperienced bidders who make systematic mistakes or are due to the potential appeal of the auction format to those who like to gamble. In a recent manuscript, Toomas Hinnosaar claims that
although penny auctions do not use any randomization devices, the equilibrium outcomes are still highly uncertain. Therefore from the individual bidder’s perspective, the auction format is similar to a lottery, which means that perhaps the definition of gambling must be extended to include auction formats like penny auctions.
Similarly, a recent paper in the journal Management Science by Brennan Platt, Joseph Price, and Henry Tappen claims:
[T]his auction is essentially a form of gambling. Like a slot machine, the bidder deposits a small fee to play, aspiring to a big payoff (of obtaining the item well below its value). The only difference is that the probabilities of winning are endogenously determined.
As I will show in this article, that line of thinking is fallacious, dangerous (insofar as it is used as a guide for policy), and unsupported by the evidence.
The problem with the above argument is that chance is fundamentally different from uncertainty. As Hinnosaar mentions, there is nothing inherently random about a penny auction. Given any set of actions, the outcome of a penny auction is entirely determined. The reason why a penny auction may seem random is that a participant does not know ahead of time what other participants will do. Furthermore, the lottery and slot machine analogies made in the above papers rely on the assumption that players use a very particular set of strategies—or, more accurately, every bidder uses the same strategy. If this were the case with penny auctions, then the stable outcome is for participants to bid at random times throughout the auction until one lucky individual wins the item. However, that sort of behavior is not generally observed in the penny auction data. One recent working paper by Joseph Goodman and another by Zhongmin Wang and Minbo Xu observe frequent bidding runs, i.e., long sequences of consecutive bids by a single auction participant, in field data. The likelihood that a pattern of random bidding would generate bidding runs of the frequencies and magnitudes observed in the data is vanishingly small.
Another problem is that even if some participants were to choose to bid randomly of their own volition, that in and of itself is not sufficient to qualify as gambling under existing law. Such a tactic is akin to a diner picking a random entrée off the menu at a restaurant that she has never been to before. There is a prize (the best entrée), consideration (the price of an entrée), and chance (the likelihood that she selects a particular entrée). She does not know ahead of time which entrée is the best. Yet this is not considered gambling because the chance is entirely manufactured by the diner. She could just as easily select any arbitrary entrée and receive an unknown, but entirely predetermined, benefit.