Navarro is an economist and director of the Office of Trade and Manufacturing Policy (OTMP), a White House agency created by President Trump. He is one of the rare economists to occupy a high-level advisory role in the White House. A Harvard University Ph.D., he is a stiff protectionist, which is rare among economists.
In June, the OTMP published a report titled “How China’s Economic Aggression Threatens the Technologies and Intellectual Property of the United States and the World.” It argues against the Chinese government’s rule-breaking mercantilism and industrial policy, which are deemed unfair, exploitative, and even extortionist. (Mercantilism includes both protectionism against imports and the promotion of exports.)
This raises the general question of what a national government’s trade policy should be toward a foreign country whose government pursues a mercantilist industrial strategy. A related issue is that Navarro himself was once a promoter of free markets and free trade (and was a contributor to this magazine in its early years). There is, of course, nothing wrong with changing one’s mind; if new evidence contradicts one’s theories, one should change one’s mind. But is today’s protectionist Navarro right, or the young, free-trade Navarro of a few decades ago?
Protectionist Evolution
In 1984, Navarro published a book titled The Policy Game: How Special Interests and Ideologues Are Stealing America. Reading it, I get the sense of a young Navarro who was a politically moderate and mainstream economist. He argued against the producers’ special interests that politically win out over consumers’ diffuse but more important interests. He blamed protectionist corporations and labor unions. He observed that protectionism “as a job program or form of income redistribution … fails miserably.” Invoking the Smoot–Haley tariff adopted at the beginning of the Great Depression, he pointed out the danger of retaliation and trade wars: “And as history has painfully taught, once protectionist wars begin, the likely result is a deadly and well-nigh unstoppable downward spiral by the entire world economy.” Elsewhere in the book he noted, “The biggest losers in the protectionist game are consumers.” He also warned against the danger of using national security as a justification for protectionism.
Fast-forward 23 years to Navarro’s 2007 book, The Coming China Wars: Where They Will Be Fought and How They Can Be Won. Largely devoid of economic analysis, it looks like a pre-write of the June OTMP report. In the book, he argues that China is a totalitarian and corrupt country on the verge of popular revolt, and that the Chinese government is trying to build an empire. Chinese producers, he charges, are guilty of unfair competition: they steal intellectual property, pay low wages, destroy the environment, and are subsidized and supported by their mercantilist government.
His fixation on the U.S. trade deficit and manufacturing industry dates from that book. He advocates environmental and labor standards for China. He speaks highly of trade unions, without which “exploitation cannot be far behind.” He lauds China’s 2006 Five-Year Plan, which was supposed to end that country’s “Adam Smith on steroids” attempt at market liberalization and replace it with government-managed “sustainable growth.”
He still wants to work within the system when he recommends using international organizations and negotiations to pressure the Chinese government to reduce its protectionism. However, he does not exclude “military might to back up the prescriptions.” He also advises the American government to stop running budget deficits that allow the Chinese government to buy Treasury securities and thereby fuel the U.S. trade deficit through upward pressure on the U.S. dollar.
He further developed and espoused his protectionist views in subsequent writings. Navarro contributed a chapter entitled “Benchmarking the Advantages Foreign Nations Provide Their Manufacturers” to the 2009 book Manufacturing a Better Future for America. The book was published by the Alliance for American Manufacturing (AAM), which describes itself as “a select group of America’s leading manufacturers and the United Steelworkers.” Navarro’s chapter provides a rare glimpse into his current theoretical framework. He argues that the conception of free trade pioneered by David Hume, Adam Smith, and David Ricardo—which lies at the foundation of the modern economic analysis of trade—is inapplicable to today’s conditions for two reasons: First it is not true that “all free trading countries … refrain from the practices of either mercantilism or protectionism.” Second, not all trading countries have automatic adjustment mechanisms that prevent chronic trade imbalances. In other words, the world is protectionist and therefore America must be, too. Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage—a cornerstone of modern economic understanding of trade—is briefly mentioned and summarily dismissed.
Navarro’s 2011 book Death by China, coauthored with Greg Autry, an assistant professor of “clinical entrepreneurship” at the University of Southern California, argues that the United States and China are in an “undeclared state of war” and that a real, non-trade war between them is possible. Consequently, American industrial capacity must be protected against Chinese competition. Navarro and Autry point out that countries in the “free world,” such as Japan, Mexico, and Germany, are “our real free trade partners.” Yet the book generally views trade and trade negotiations as analogous to war. Trade unions must protect jobs against shoddy and dangerous Chinese products. A companion documentary film, produced by Autry and partly financed by steelmaker Nucor, is even more radically protectionist.
In 2015, Navarro published Crouching Tiger: What China’s Militarism Means for the World. It deals mainly with a future military confrontation between the United States and China, and ways to prevent it if possible. It too has a companion documentary, subtitled “Will There Be a War with China?” In both, Navarro argues that the U.S. government must build a strong military advantage over China with the help of its allies. American consumers must stop financing China’s own military expansion with their purchases of Chinese goods. A “trade rebalancing” would “slow China’s economy and thereby its rapid military buildup,” according to the book. “It would also provide America and its allies with both the strong growth and manufacturing base these countries need to build their own comprehensive national power.”
Last June, the news and commentary website Axios prodded Navarro on why he had changed his opinions on trade so radically after The Policy Game. He explained that after China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001, he realized that free trade cannot work when it is not fair—for example, when one of the countries involved practices “non–market economy industrial policies.” “The traditional approach to evaluating tariffs,” he wrote for Axios, “ignores the external costs or ‘negative externalities’ associated with unfair trade.” These “externalities” include the loss of factories, jobs, and incomes, and their consequences in workers’ lives.
In his writings, Navarro makes five distinct arguments against open trade with China and other countries. They can be summarized as follows:
- The impossible-competition argument: We cannot compete against a dirigiste and even totalitarian country like China. Trying to do so generates negative externalities.
- The fairness argument: “Unfair” trade is not free trade and is destroying the American economy.
- The trade deficit argument: The U.S. trade deficit is a serious problem that reduces gross domestic product and indicates unfair trade.
- The retaliation argument: Retaliatory protectionist measures are justified against protectionist countries; such retaliators are the real free-traders.
- The national security argument: Protectionism is required for reasons of national security.
Many of these arguments are now echoed by large groups of the America public. I examine each of them in the following sections.
The Impossible-Competition Argument
Navarro and others invoke China as an extreme case that authoritarian governments make for bad trading partners. Of course, he is right to describe the Chinese state as authoritarian and repressive, if not totalitarian.
In 2012, Nobel economics laureate Ronald Coase and co-author Ning Wang of Arizona State University published a book titled How China Became Capitalist, describing the country’s economic evolution after the accession of liberalizer Deng Xiaoping in 1978. (See “Getting Rich Is Glorious,” Winter 2012–2013, and “The Power of Exchange: Ronald H. Coase 1910–2013,” Winter 2013–2014.) However, conventional wisdom holds that those reforms have been reversed in recent years.
Economic freedom in China / But things are not as simple as the conventional wisdom—and Navarro—suggest. Consider China’s scores on the Fraser Institute’s Economic Freedom of the World index (FTW). The index combines indicators of the size of government, commitment to the rule of law and property rights, soundness of the national currency, freedom to trade internationally, and scope of regulation. An index like this must be used with caution, but China’s scores over time suggest the country continues to make progress—albeit sometimes haltingly—toward economic freedom.
Figure 1 compares China’s overall FTW score to the United States’ in recent years. Perfect freedom would get a score of 10. Economic freedom in China increased markedly from 1980 (the first year available) through the years preceding the country’s accession to the WTO in 2001, with the exception of a dip around the time of the Tiananmen Square events and Deng’s retirement in 1989. Economic freedom in China has continued to rise since 2001, although more slowly.
In the United States, on the contrary, economic freedom as measured by the FTW has generally decreased since 2000. Obviously, freedom is much more advanced in America, but the comparative trend is interesting. (Another index of economic freedom, compiled by the Heritage Foundation, shows the United States dropping from the “free country” category to “mostly free” in 2010.)
Figure 2 charts the index component “Freedom to trade internationally,” which measures the absence of domestic barriers to trade. The figure suggests this freedom has been declining in the United States while, in China, it dramatically increased until 2001, and has remained more or less constant since. Over the whole period 1980–2015, the change in the freedom to trade more than explains the change in the total economic freedom index for both China and the United States. Given those trends, it is not clear that the Chinese government has become less of a free trader.
In their 2011 book, Navarro and Autry characterized the Chinese economic system as a “brand of state capitalism,” which is not false. But if we want to speak in those terms, it can be argued that the American system is another brand of state capitalism (or crony capitalism), as the current protectionist push illustrates. And Ning Wang remains optimistic for China; in comments to me he indicated his belief that “overall, China is still on its way to capitalism.”
Convenient scapegoat / Many arguments against Chinese imports are exaggerated. In Death by China, Navarro and Autry wrote that “China has stolen millions of American manufacturing jobs” and that “if we had held onto those jobs, America’s unemployment would be well below 5%.” In writing this they confounded macroeconomic factors and trade issues. In May 2016, five years after their book was published, the U.S. unemployment rate was 4.7%, and it has continued declining ever since.
How to explain the low unemployment given the jobs “lost” to China and elsewhere? They were replaced—and then some—by other jobs. During the so-called “China shock” between 1999 and 2011, when U.S. imports from China grew rapidly and job disruptions followed (in certain manufacturing industries), 5.6 million net jobs were created in the U.S. economy.
Jobs are a poor measure of worker welfare, of course; otherwise, destroying machines and computers would be good policy because more workers would then be required. What matters is income. During the same period, real U.S. income (real GDP) increased by 26%. All this occurred despite the worst recession since the Great Depression.
The value of the goods imported from China is also often exaggerated. According to research done at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, the proportion of American consumer expenditures that go to China, including the value of the Chinese inputs incorporated into what’s produced in America, is 1.9%. This is because Chinese goods occupy a big share only in relatively small categories of consumer expenditures (such as clothing and shoes, or furniture and household equipment), and because two-thirds of what Americans consume is composed of domestic services—such things as health care, education, and housing.
Irrational fear / But isn’t Chinese industrial policy a great threat? No. It is an error to believe, contra economic theory and history, that the controlled enterprises in a country dominated by a communist government can constitute a grave danger for efficient capitalist enterprises. No private car manufacturer would have feared import competition from Trabants, the shoddy East German cars whose production did not survive the fall of the Berlin Wall.
In the 1970s and 1980s, similar fears were expressed about Japanese industrial policy and the country’s supposedly all-powerful Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI). There was no comparison between Trabants and Japanese cars such as Hondas or Toyotas: Japanese cars were state-of-the-art machines built by private companies. Yet the threat to the U.S. economy posed by the Japanese turned out to be greatly exaggerated.
If China is backsliding from a market economy, then Western producers have little to fear. And if China isn’t backsliding and its producers make advances in freedom and economic efficiency, then that is good for all of mankind. Competition from state-dominated businesses, even if “unfair,” is not a big threat, and fair competition from capitalist firms can only be good, whether that competition is domestic or foreign.
Externality argument / Navarro’s “externality” argument is remarkably shoddy. First, note that outcompeting producers is not technically an “externality,” but the normal result of a free and flexible economy where “creative destruction” occurs. If the result of competition is considered an externality, everything in economic life is an externality and the concept becomes useless.