Now, I’ll be the first to admit that the Fed could have a major negative effect on short-term market interest rates if it chose to do so. The Fed could, for instance, raise reserve requirements while rapidly selling large quantities of its assets. This action would remove a massive amount of liquidity from the market. But that’s exactly why the Fed isn’t about to do it.
Like it or not, the Fed is the lender of last resort (I.E., the ultimate source of liquidity) and it’s charged with stamping out risks to financial stability. It isn’t about to purposely make liquidity incredibly scarce.
Finally, it is not entirely clear that credit markets, broadly, have become particularly tight as rates have ratcheted up. While it is difficult to measure just how tight credit markets have become, at least one Fed metric suggests they’re not particularly tight and that conditions have been easing since October 2022. (Commercial banks have been lending more through the Fed’s tightening cycle, and according to SIFMA data, repo market volume is up in 2022. But these types of metrics describe only narrow pieces of financial markets.)
At the macro level, retail sales have been mostly growing since 2020, and both gross domestic private investment and net domestic investment by private businesses have basically trended up since 2021. Industrial production has been on a generally upward trend (though it did decline from October through December), and GDP has barely missed a beat.
If the Fed really has been trying to “slow down the economy,” it hasn’t done it. Yet, inflation has been falling.
Obviously, it’s important to figure out exactly why inflation spiked in the first place, and why it is falling. My money is on stimulative fiscal policy worsening the effects of COVID shutdowns, not monetary policy. And the Fed accommodated that fiscal burst.
Speaking of which, we have an even bigger problem than in years past because the Fed can now accommodate fiscal policy more easily than before. That is, the Fed can now purchase financial assets without creating the types of inflationary pressures that those purchases would have created prior to 2008.
Congress can address this problem by imposing a cap on the size of the Fed’s balance sheet and on the portion of outstanding U.S. debt the Fed can hold. Longer-term, though, it’s time for Congress to ditch the current system precisely because it depends on a central bank to “speed up the economy” to stave off deflation and to “slow down the economy” to fight inflation.
A better alternative would be to narrow the Fed’s legislative mandate while leveling the regulatory playing field between the U.S. dollar and other potential means of payment. There are many good reasons the Fed should not be targeting prices, and allowing competitive private markets to provide currency would present a powerful a check on the government’s ability to diminish the quality of money.